Among the most well-known of the classical economists is
David Ricardo. Known particularly for the concept of comparative advantage and
how it—and not absolute advantage or
any other measure—should be the basis for trade between individuals or nations
(making trade no longer a zero-sum game), Ricardo is also well-known for laying
out the theory behind what is known as Ricardian Equivalence. While he doubted
the real-world existence of this proposition (and Robert Barro’s subsequent
work in the 1970’s seemingly finding evidence for it is still frequently
discussed), Ricardian Equivalence essentially states that taxpayers are
rational and infinitely (or close to infinitely) forward-looking. Thus, they
internalize the government’s budget constraint, such that they understand that
a decrease in tax rates today must imply an increase
in tax rates in the future. Instead of spending their tax cut and
increasing Consumption (which might be the desire of government officials
engaging in expansionary fiscal policy), they will save that money knowing that
they will be taxed at a higher rate later. In short, this implies a relative
ineffectiveness of fiscal policy (whether expansionary or contractionary) on
Consumption and thus on GDP and economic growth.
This proposition assumes of course that there is no dominant
wealth effect (thus, that a tax cut today would not be more than compensated for by the
larger wealth of subsequent generations, making a tax cut in essence
self-financing), that taxpayers are rational, and that they are very-forward
looking. Those are of course strong assumptions; we know there are a myriad of
biases, egocentric and temporal errors, myopia and temporal discounting, among
other decision-making factors that make taxpayers (and economic agents in
general) particularly “irrational” actors. On top of that, of course, much has
happened between the time of Smith, Ricardo, Mill, Malthus, etc., and economic
thought has evolved correspondingly. Heckscher and Ohlin, for example, have
built upon the theory of comparative advantage to include factors of production
and in turn help explain sources of comparative advantage.
In a world where public finance has been a central topic of
political discourse all around the world, it is essential that economics reach
comprehensive and accurate responses to a large number of questions: What is
the role of public debt on economic growth and taxpayer behavior? Does deficit
spending (with the explicit purpose of stimulating the economy) actually work?
Is Ricardian equivalence empirically observed? If so, is its effect different
between expansionary or contractionary fiscal policy? How forward-looking are
taxpayers? Are tax cuts self-financing? Is there a wealth effect? Do the
answers to these questions vary based on demographic makeup, political
leanings, or social inclinations of the population under study? And finally,
based on the answers to these questions, what is the appropriate tax and fiscal
policy to ensure the proper balance between economic growth,
the social and political goals of each population, and the proper management of
the nation’s resources and what is in essence each generation’s intertemporal
responsibility: leave behind a better and more prosperous society (for all)
than the one they were born into?
No comments:
Post a Comment